A Case Against Privatisation: Part 2
Welcome back! Towards the end of the 20th century, the provisioning of water saw a shift from state monopolies to a gradual increase in private sector involvement, which inevitably has been a topic of much discussion. Additionally, access to safe drinking water and sanitation has been established by the United Nations (UN) in 2010 as a human right, questioning the ethics of commodifying a natural resource that is necessary for human survival. In this blog, I’ll be exploring the arguments against the increasing involvement of the private sector.
Private sector limitations
The limitations of private sector
involvement have been identified in Bayliss
(2003). The first being the effectiveness of privatising the delivery of
water is dependent on the government’s organisational structure that precedes private
sector involvement. Countries that had a relatively functioning supply chain
tended to continue being functional post privatisation; the reverse was true
for dysfunctional supply chains. Additionally, the success of the delivery of
water is dependent on the wider economic environment, whereby unfavourable political,
economic or social climates can detrimentally impact the success of private
operators. I discussed in my last
blog the effectiveness of Cote d’Ivoire’s privatised delivery service, however,
performance dropped after political unrest began in 2002 ultimately leading to
SODECI withdrawing their operations (Bayliss, 2003).
Secondly, a major weakness of
privatisation has been the private sectors failure to comply with regulations.
This can also be attributed to a lack of regulatory capacity available in an
associated administration; a condition that is rather wide spread throughout many
low income countries. The strong rule of law and its ability to be enforced is
fundamental to holding the private sector accountable, and is something that is
just assumed to be available in governments of low income countries. This reinforces
the imbalance in power between the private operators and their regulators. This
asymmetry is highly undesirable in developing economies where particular groups
are highly vulnerable to exploitation (Bayliss, 2003).
Furthermore, the benefits of the
private sector, particularly with respect to efficiency and performance rely
heavily on market conditions that facilitate relatively low risk investment and
therefore competition. Unfortunately, many places in Africa currently do not lend
themselves to these market conditions. Private operators need to generate profit
which remains challenging in low income countries where portions of the
population are unable to afford the water being supplied, ultimately reducing
financial backing. This in turn reduces competition which can undermine some of
the benefits resulting from private sector involvement. An example being the
withdrawal of Biwater from supplying water in Zimbabwe as the service was
unaffordable to many. Not to mention, the required profit margin for private firms
is likely to result in rural areas being excluded from the supply chain as
urban areas are much more economically viable (Bayliss, 2003).
Prepaid meters – Harare, Zimbabwe |
Ultimately, the effectiveness of
private sector relies heavily on the effectiveness of government with regards
to; maintaining appropriate economic conditions in which the private sector can
operate; executing it’s regulatory power to ensure balance of power; and
potentially provide subsidies to private firms when consumers are unable to
afford the service in an effort to stimulate investment (Bayliss, 2003).
Runaway privatisation
Bayliss goes on to argue in her
later work that another issue of privatisation is that it can lay the
foundations for financialisaton Bayliss (2014).
This could be seen as an unintended
consequence whereby the treatment of water as a private commodity with economic
value feeds into the financial market of stocks and assets, whose participants
are financial elites operating on national and international levels; a stark
contrast to the ‘small scale entrepreneurs’ Solo
was heavily promoting, as I mentioned in my last
blog. Furthermore, Bayliss clearly states the issues with the intensifying financialisaton
of water, specifically; it’s direct association with increasing wealth
inequality; detracting investment from the real economy (the part of the economy
related to goods and services production) to high value assets; the tendency of
global elites operating in the financial market to safeguard inequitable and exploitative
influence in policy-making, particularly at national levels; and it’s prioritisation
of profit over equity.
To conclude…
Privatisation has fundamental limitations
that can hinder its ability to function. Additionally, effective privatisation doesn’t
necessarily relieve government of its obligations, rather shifts it to a more
regulatory focus, challenging many African governments. In this regard, a
strong government is required for either state monopolies or privatisation, no
matter the degree of involvement, so the sentiment of privatisation being a
panacea for supply of water is arguably not well founded.
Reference List
Bayliss, K 2003, Utility privatisation in Sub-Saharan Africa: a case study of water,
The Journal of Modern African Studies, Cambridge, Vol. 41, Iss.4.
Bayliss, K 2014, The Finacialisation of Water, Review of
Radical Political Economics, Vol 46(2) 292-307.
Solo, T.M. (1999) Small-scale entrepreneurs in the urban water
sanitation market. Environment and Urbanisation, Vol. 11, No.1 Pp 117-132.
UN Resolution 64/292, adopted by the
General Assembly, July 2010.
This post was very interesting and different from what I have read before in the blogs about this topic. I really liked your discussion about the effectiveness of privatisation and it's requirements. The arguments were very clear so well done!
ReplyDeleteHi, thank you for your nice comment, I'l glad you found the post interesting.
Delete